Skip to main content

Medicaid Expansion: A Raw Deal


For the sake of most Oklahomans, our state legislature should continue to hold out against the unrelenting pressure of monied interests and refuse to expand the state’s Medicaid program under Obamacare. Why? It’s simple, really, if someone is robbing my house, moving from room to room and taking my valuables, I’m not going to point out a room they missed and invite them to steal even more. Expanding Medicaid will just allow the health industry to take even more from us than they already do.

That’s the fundamental, underlying message of my most recent paper, Medicaid Expansion in Colorado: An Exercise in Futility. In addition to providing some context about just how rich the health industry is in this country, I use plain language to restate the conclusions of an official study from a Colorado state agency to point out that Medicaid expansion advocates (mostly from the health care industry) are selling us a false bill of goods.

The false claim is that if we expand Medicaid, currently uninsured patients who do not pay their bills will have their bills paid by Medicaid. This will allow hospitals to lower prices for the rest of us since prices are high at least partly to make up for the freeloaders.

The Colorado study shows that when Medicaid was expanded, hospitals raised their prices even faster than they had in the past, exactly opposite the claims of the health industry’s Medicaid expansion advocates. And this hasn’t just happened in Colorado. A study out of Arizona shows exactly the same phenomenon. I suspect we’d find the same in nearly every one of the 36 Medicaid-expanding states. And, we’d see the same thing right here.

Surely, you might think, there has to be something wrong with these studies. After all, it makes sense that prices have to be raised to make up for losses suffered when some don’t pay their bills. There’s even a name for it, “cost shifting”, where the costs of treating the uninsured are shifted to the insured. Surely that’s a real phenomenon and Medicaid expansion could reverse it.

But these studies expose the reality that cost shifting, like other explanations of why health care is so expensive, is used by the health care industry to confuse us. They say new technology raises costs, but in every other industry since the dawn of man, improved technology lowers costs and prices. They say costs are high because they have to treat everybody in emergency rooms, but the Reagan-era law they reference only says someone has to be treated and stabilized if they have life-threatening injuries. They claim that emergency room treatment is very expensive, but never explain why, even when emergency rooms experience high volumes, where high volumes reduce per-unit costs in other industries.

Still, you might be thinking, none of this explains why health care prices would rise even as health care gets more money from Medicaid. That’s true. So far I’ve only given examples of how we are easily distracted. 

The fact is that when the health industry gets more government money, it raises prices because that’s how the industry claims all the money it was making before PLUS the new Medicaid money. That’s how it is that health care claims nearly a fifth of Americans’ incomes. That’s how it is that 13 of the 15 highest-paid professions are in health care. That’s how it is that less than 10 percent of employed Americans (those in health care) claim twice that level of America’s total income.

The most difficult argument to overcome in favor of expanding Medicaid, though, is that for a mere $100 million, Oklahoma will get $1 billion of its own money back from the federal government. This money, it is said, will benefit all Oklahomans as it is spent here, and improve our economy. This is tough to refute, but it’s not impossible.

First, our unemployment rate is below 4 percent, essentially at full employment. More money in health care will only distort the economy more than it is now, and it’s not as if people are dying from lack of health care. The industry has the money to take care of anyone who really needs help, as shown in an earlier 1889 Institute study of hospital finances.

Second, the health industry is so wealthy that it’s debatable just how much new money spent on it would stay in the state. Odds are, it would just go to buy vacation homes in Jackson Hole or in The Hamptons.

Third, “a billion for a mere tenth of that” sounds a lot like “you must buy this since it’s on sale.” The result is rarely a happy one. And this is especially true when it’s been demonstrated that the sale is a raw deal.

And that’s the upshot of the Colorado and Arizona studies. Medicaid expansion is a raw deal. It only allows the richest sector in our economy to take even more from us, not out of necessity, and not for any benefit to the rest of us, but simply because it can.

Byron Schlomach is Director of the 1889 Institute and can be reached at bschlomach@1889institute.org.


Popular posts from this blog

1889 Institute's Statement Regarding School Closures

The 1889 Institute, an Oklahoma think tank, has released the following statement regarding Joy Hofmeister’s proposal to keep schools closed for the remainder of the school year. We at the 1889 Institute consider Joy Hofmeister’s proposal to close Oklahoma’s schools for the rest of the school year a gross overreaction to the coronavirus situation. Even in the best of times and circumstances, suddenly shifting every student in the state from traditional classrooms to online distance learning will have negative educational consequences. This in addition to the economic burden on two-earner families forced to completely reorder their lives with schools closed. We believe many of our leaders have overreacted to worst-case scenarios presented by well-intended health experts with no training or sense of proportion in weighing the collateral damage of shutting down our economy versus targeting resources to protect the truly vulnerable. We say reopen the schools and stop the madness. ...

Can Government Force You to Close Your Business?

1889 Institute takes no position on whether any or all of these measures are warranted or necessary, or whether their economic fallout would inflict more human suffering than they prevent. We are simply evaluating whether they are legal.   With the unprecedented (in the last 100 years at least) reaction surrounding the outbreak of Covid-19, questions that few living legal scholars have considered are suddenly relevant.   Can a quarantine be ordered?   Can a mass quarantine, lockdown, or “cordon sanitaire” be ordered? Can businesses be ordered to change their behavior?   Can businesses be ordered to close? Can state governments order these measures? Can local governments order these measures? My legal brief addresses these issues from a statutory point of view; it is clear that state law gives the governor and mayors broad authority in a state of emergency. They must, of course, do so in a neutral way that they reasonably believe will help preve...

Destroying Others’ Property Is Violence, No Matter How It’s Done

With characterizations of protests and riots that have occurred over the last several months as “mostly peaceful” and headlines that include “peaceful demonstration intensified,” and “Fiery But Mostly Peaceful Protests,” it’s clear many in the press do not consider property destruction to be violent. Most likely, they mean most of the protesters haven’t physically harmed anyone. Still, during the very same protests, a large proportion of the “peaceful” participants , in obvious acts of aggression and hostility, have vandalized and stolen property. In fact, property destruction and theft are acts of violence, and are therefore legitimately defended against, not because these acts feel threatening, but because they are, in and of themselves, violent.   Nevertheless, it’s common to hear many condemn individuals who use or threaten force in defense of their property. After all, if no one is physically harmed, or even actually threatened, how can damaging inanimate objects possibl...

Oklahoma Elections: For Insiders Only?

When is election day? Most people probably assume it’s the first Tuesday in November. That makes sense, since that’s the date for statewide elections, and, in even numbered years, federal elections as well. Would it surprise you to learn that there is an election scheduled in Oklahoma every single month in 2019? That is not to say that every district has an election every month. That would be a hassle - the well-engaged citizen would have to make it to his local precinct every 4 weeks to make sure his views are adequately expressed. The slipshod way local elections are scheduled is far more shocking and less predictable than that. One would be forgiven for thinking, on first glance, that Oklahoma allows government bodies to change lawmakers and raise taxes through oddly scheduled, poorly noticed elections on (almost) whichever Tuesday they want. However, in reality there are “only” 15 days per year when local elections can be scheduled. Still, this means that the party in p...