Skip to main content

Protecting Your Rights: Interpreting Law by Its Plain Meaning


When deciding whether people have broken laws, should judges consider the intent of the legislators who wrote the law? Or simply consider the plain language of the law as written? Legal scholars have debated this question for decades. However, there is only one answer that protects We The People.

The Declaration of Independence states, “Governments are instituted among Men, deriving their just powers from the consent of the governed.” This means, among other things, that only laws actually voted on by the people (or their validly elected representatives) can be legitimately enforced. Any purpose not written into the law was not voted on, and so should not be imposed.


What does this have to do with interpreting laws? In the republican form of government, the citizens speak through their elected representatives. These representatives pass laws collectively, almost always through two legislative bodies (House and Senate) and an executive (President or Governor) signs off. Even in relatively small states, that’s a considerable number of people who have to agree for an idea to become a law. Odds are that there are several purposes at work to enact a single law.


Judges making guesses as to this unwritten legislative intent when penalizing a citizen is unfair, inconsistent, and unconstitutional. A judge might think he knows why legislators enacted a law, but legislators cast their votes for all kinds of reasons. We hope they do so for the public good. But some do so for selfish reasons. Some vote for a policy they dislike to curry favor for something they deem more important. Expanding a law beyond the plain text violates these first principles of representative government by consent of the governed. It also fails to put the public on notice as to what conduct is prohibited. What the judge believes to have been the legislative intent is not law. And judges are not appointed to make policy.


Imagine a law passed by a 5-member city council, prohibiting “vehicles in the park.” It passes by a vote of five to zero. But what qualifies as a vehicle? Does a bike? A dirt bike? A wheelchair? Does it apply only to street-legal vehicles? The first councilman lives near the park, and doesn’t like the noise of motorized vehicles near his house. He would allow bikes and wheelchairs but not dirt bikes. The second is an extreme environmentalist, and fears that anything with wheels will damage the fragile ecology of the park. He would not allow any of the potential “vehicles,” including bikes and wheelchairs. The third has a child with a physical handicap who needs a wheelchair, enjoys the park, but is frightened by bikes speeding past. He would allow wheelchairs but not bikes or dirt bikes. The fourth rides a dirt bike, and wants to keep cars and larger vehicles out of the park to ensure the path is clear for him to ride. He would allow all three. The fifth is indifferent, but votes for the ordinance to be agreeable. It is unclear what he would allow.


That’s two “for,” two “against,” and one “undecided” on bicycles; three “for,” one “against,” and one “undecided” on wheelchairs, and one “for,” three “against,” and one “undecided” on dirt bikes. If the judge and the public could read the minds of the legislators, it would be clear that dirt bikes are prohibited, wheelchairs are allowed, and it is unclear regarding bicycles. But the judge and the public can’t read minds. They can read the text of the law.

More importantly, the five members of the council didn’t agree on any one purpose. They didn’t reach a majority consensus. They only agreed that “vehicles” were prohibited.  So, no intention has been enacted by the consent of the people. Only the text of the law has been voted on, so only the text of the law is legitimately enacted.


So where does that leave principled textualists, who eschew constructing legislative intent? As much as possible, judges should give words in laws their commonly understood meaning. Because of this law’s lack of written purpose or definitions, there is still an ambiguity to be resolved: can someone be ticketed for riding their bicycle, dirt bike or wheelchair through the park? One answer is found in traditional definitions, easily accessible to the general public: the dictionary.


Dictionary definitions may sound trite, but they are often useful interpretive tools. Merriam Webster defines vehicle as “a means of carrying or transporting something (planes, trains, and other vehicles) such as a: MOTOR VEHICLE b: a piece of mechanized equipment.”


This textual source provides judges with black and white guidance, fair to the general public, that bikes and wheelchairs are okay (they are not mechanized), whereas motorized dirt bikes are prohibited. If the judge felt a ticket for a bicycle was too close to call, since it has some mechanized parts, he could also invoke the “rule of lenity”: where an ambiguous law is interpreted in favor of the accused. Here, that would likely allow bikes in the park. The City Council could always revise the law to prohibit them. This seems to be a just result, even though it doesn’t fully capture each member of the council’s intended prohibitions. 

The road to hell is paved with guesses at legislative intent. The road to a well-functioning republic, based on the consent of the governed, is paved with reliance on the actual text of the law.


Mike Davis is Research Fellow at 1889 Institute. He can be reached at mdavis@1889institute.org.

The opinions expressed in this blog are those of the author, and do not necessarily reflect the official position of 1889 Institute.


Popular posts from this blog

Licensing Boards Might Violate Federal Law: Regardless, They Are Terrible Policy

Competition is as American as baseball and apple pie. “May the best man win” is a sentiment so old it doesn’t care about your pronouns. The beneficial effects of competition on economic markets are well documented. So why do we let powerful business interests change the rules of the game when they tire of competing in the free market? Most of the time when an occupational license is enacted, it is the members of the regulated industry who push hardest in favor of the license. Honest competition may be fundamentally American, but thwarting that competition through licensing seems to be fundamentally Oklahoman. Oklahoma doesn’t have the most occupational licenses, but when they do license an occupation, the requirements tend to be more onerous than the same license in other states. But what if, instead of merely breaking the rules of fair play to keep out would-be competition, Oklahoma licensing boards are also breaking the law? Normally a concerted effort to lock out competition would v

Undo 802

Why is it that when conservatives suffer a major loss, they give up, accept the new status quo, and fall back to the next retreat position? When progressives suffer a major loss, they regroup and try again. And again. Until they finally wheedle the American public into giving in. I propose a change in strategy. The Oklahoma Legislature should make undoing State Question 802 its top legislative priority for 2021. This will not be an easy task (legislators seem to prefer avoiding difficult tasks) but it is a critical one. The normal legislative process, with all its pitfalls and traps for the unwary, will only bring the topic to another vote of the people. So why spend so much political capital and effort if the same result is possible? Three reasons.   First is the disastrous consequences of the policy. Forget that it enriches already-rich hospital and pharmaceutical executives. Forget that it gives the state incentives to prioritize the nearly-poor covered by expansion over the des

COVID-1984: Have Americans Become Too Complacent in Our Liberties?

Alongside the coronavirus, another pandemic is gripping our country, one that we will feel the consequences of long after we reach herd immunity. I dub this pandemic COVID-1984, and I fear it will rot the roots of the Tree of Liberty. The consequence will be a government emboldened by a passive citizenry. One of the most surprising aspects of our current situation is how willing people have been to report their fellow citizens to authorities for the most minor and meaningless offenses. I used to wonder how people in authoritarian countries like Stalinist Russia and Maoist China went along with those cruel regimes. It turns out a tiny bit of fear is all you need to be a successful dictator. And now it’s all the easier to report your neighbors for reading alone on the beach with tip lines.   Even as governors and judges begin to lift stay at home orders, mayors are extending them. A county judge issued a temporary restraining order against Illinois Governor J.B. Pritzker’s stay at

A Minimum Wage Hike is Bad for Oklahomans - Especially Those at or Near Minimum Wage

Proposed minimum wage hikes have sprung up across the country, and Oklahoma is not immune . Here is why a minimum wage hike will hurt Oklahomans.   What happens when the price of something goes up? Take oil, for instance. As of this writing, the price of oil is just above $59 a barrel. Imagine the Oklahoma legislature set a minimum price for oil, and that number doubled. If gas went from $2.50 a gallon to $5 or more would it change your behavior? Would you drive less? I know I would. This is a basic illustration of the laws of supply and demand . As the price goes up, demand goes down. This is true for oil. People would still have to get to work, but they might rethink that summer road trip. Those who live near the border might drive farther to buy gas from a neighboring state. These same principles hold true for all commodities.   Why wouldn’t it apply just as much to labor ? If you have to pay more for each employee-hour worked, wouldn’t you start to cut back on the nu