Skip to main content

Welfare of Oklahoma’s Children Panned In Flawed “Study”


Are Oklahoma’s children underprivileged? According to a recently published list by Wallethub, which attempted to rank states with the most underprivileged children, Oklahoma is the 7th worst. However, if the goal was to help states improve their policies, or to show parents what states to avoid, the authors might have done better to provide sources for their data (outside the lists Wallethub had already compiled), and more importantly, choose better metrics. The authors don’t provide much context or support for why their chosen metrics matter, or how they could be changed. Of course, the goal might just be clicks. 


The study is divided into three sections: Socio-economic welfare (50 points), health (25 points), and education (25 points). Each is evaluated based on Wallethubs list of arbitrary metrics and then assigned a weighted score. These are then combined to get the final overall underprivileged” score. But are these scores worthwhile? 


Socio-economic Welfare


Share of Children Living in Extreme Poverty: Wallethub defines extreme poverty as having an income less than 250 percent of the federal poverty line. For an individual, that is about $32,000 a year. For a family of 3, it is approximately $54,000 per year. Does that sound like “extreme poverty?” The World Bank defines extreme poverty as living on $1.90 or less a day. Wallethubs measure defines it as living on less than $87.40 a day for an individual or less than $148.77 for a family of 3. The calculus seems a bit off here. In addition, the list fails account for cost of living. $54,000 a year goes much further in rural Oklahoma than it does in Manhattan.

Economic mobility: This term is completely undefined. Wallethub fails to specify whether theyre measuring the economic mobility of the children, their parents or the entire family. They also do not mention how they measure economic mobility. 

Children in Renter vs. Owner Households: This metric is under-explained and its inclusion is unjustified. Is the child of a military family, who moves every year and finds renting base housing more efficient than buying and selling, underprivileged? Is a child whose parents own a hovel privileged? Certainly home ownership has long been a way to pass wealth from one generation to the next, but a wealth of counterexamples cast doubt on the contention that children in renter households are de facto less privileged than those in owner households.   

Health

Coronavirus Infrastructure: This metric is given triple weight. This is a pointless measure to include, especially as those aged 0-17 are already at an incredibly low risk of contracting and dying from COVID. It is also a measure that is of temporary use, as pandemics dont last forever. Any attempt to repeat the study would have to eliminate or replace this metric.

Share of Adolescents 9th to 12th Grade Who Felt Sad or Hopeless During the Past Year: This metric could just as easily be called “Number of High School Students in the State.” What is the government supposed to do about angsty teens? Even rich and privileged teens get sad or feel hopeless. Again, Wallethub fails to cite a source for their data or even specify how it was gathered. Nor do they explain why teens specifically are counted in this measure but those below high school age are not. Persistent feelings of sadness and hopelessness lasting more than 2 weeks can be a sign of depression. But the Wallethub study does not specify a period of time and has a separate measure for depression. 

Share of Children Suffering from Depression: Is depression an ailment that only affects the underprivileged? Of course not. It afflicts people from a variety of backgrounds and financial situations. Furthermore, what policy could states implement to fight this? It's not the role of government to hand out antidepressants. 

Education

Young Children Not Enrolled in School: Wallethub defines young children as 3-4 years old, so this measure is solely about pre-K. Oklahoma already provides universal, voluntary pre-K education for 4 year olds. Studies indicate that pre-K may not provide any significant benefit to children. One study in particular found that by 3rd grade, participants in a pre-k program were actually behind their peers (who were eligible for the program but lost the lottery for entry). Inclusions of such faulty metrics casts doubts on Wallethub’s methods.   

State Pre-K Funding per Preschool-Aged Resident: As stated above, Oklahoma already offers universal pre-K education. Again, Pre-K education is of limited benefit to children. Studies have shown that while it did provide an advantage in early childhood education, that advantage had largely faded by the time the children reached grade school. Even supporters of pre-K education acknowledge that it might not be the best use of scarce resources. In addition, success should be measured by outcomes rather than funding. Government programs should be evaluated based on measurable outcomes and financial efficiency, not the amount of taxpayer dollars poured into them.

Wallethub's entry into the public policy space is puzzling, to say the least. It would be one thing if they were merely using a catchy top-50 ranking to drive traffic to their website to sell ads and get affiliate click-throughs to new credit cards. But there appears to be a concerted effort to shape public policy. They polled no less than 15 experts, all with advanced degrees, asking a series of questions to each. Unfortunately, they failed to ask the right questions. If the idea is to push government to make better policy, the metrics must be both things government can (and should) control, and they should measure the results of the government policy, rather than the inputs. If Texas bragged that they spent 5 billion dollars digging a hole in the ground to educate their kids, Oklahomans would be justified in mocking them. Results do not care how hard you tried or how much money you spent. Results show how well you performed. Bad policy is bad policy no matter how much money you pour into it. Let’s make sure we continue ask how well our government has performed.


Spencer Cadavero is a Research Associate at 1889 institute and can be reached at scadavero@1889institute.org.

Tyler Williamson is a Research Associate at 1889 institute and can be reached at twilliamson@1889institute.org.


The opinions expressed in this blog are those of the authors, and do not necessarily reflect the official position of 1889 Institute.

Popular posts from this blog

Undo 802

Why is it that when conservatives suffer a major loss, they give up, accept the new status quo, and fall back to the next retreat position? When progressives suffer a major loss, they regroup and try again. And again. Until they finally wheedle the American public into giving in. I propose a change in strategy. The Oklahoma Legislature should make undoing State Question 802 its top legislative priority for 2021. This will not be an easy task (legislators seem to prefer avoiding difficult tasks) but it is a critical one. The normal legislative process, with all its pitfalls and traps for the unwary, will only bring the topic to another vote of the people. So why spend so much political capital and effort if the same result is possible? Three reasons.   First is the disastrous consequences of the policy. Forget that it enriches already-rich hospital and pharmaceutical executives. Forget that it gives the state incentives to prioritize the nearly-poor covered by expansion over the des

Licensing Boards Might Violate Federal Law: Regardless, They Are Terrible Policy

Competition is as American as baseball and apple pie. “May the best man win” is a sentiment so old it doesn’t care about your pronouns. The beneficial effects of competition on economic markets are well documented. So why do we let powerful business interests change the rules of the game when they tire of competing in the free market? Most of the time when an occupational license is enacted, it is the members of the regulated industry who push hardest in favor of the license. Honest competition may be fundamentally American, but thwarting that competition through licensing seems to be fundamentally Oklahoman. Oklahoma doesn’t have the most occupational licenses, but when they do license an occupation, the requirements tend to be more onerous than the same license in other states. But what if, instead of merely breaking the rules of fair play to keep out would-be competition, Oklahoma licensing boards are also breaking the law? Normally a concerted effort to lock out competition would v

Cronyism: Feature, Not a Bug, for Used Car Dealer Licensing

Used car dealers in Oklahoma are governed by the Oklahoma Used Motor Vehicle and Parts Commission (UMPV). Like most licensing boards, it is made up of industry insiders. The UMVP's stated mission is to protect consumers from harm, but its structure and history indicate that its primary concern might be protecting licensed dealers from competition. This, of course, is the prime directive of all licensing boards. My recent paper deals with the licensing of used car dealers.   The person hit hardest by this is the hobbyist, especially in times of economic turmoil.   Imagine someone stuck at home due to coronavirus. We'll call him Frank. He can’t work due to the economic shutdown. Unfortunately, Frank’s lack of work does not mean he no longer has to put food on the table for his family. Fortunately for him, he is able to find a good deal on a used car that needs a little work. Frank has all the tools and garage space necessary to fix up the car and isn't violating any quar

The Real Reason Health Care Prices Keep Rising

Much has been made of the healthcare crisis of late, but very little of it addresses two of the biggest financial problems with the system: the third party payer problem and the reality that health insurance bears no resemblance to true insurance.   Insurance is a pooling of risk. The odds are that just over one in every 250 people will contract cancer in the next year. Cancer is an incredibly expensive disease to treat. So if 250 people got together and put aside enough savings to cover one case of cancer between them, they have effectively pooled their risk, and, on average, they should have enough to cover the statistical cancer they as a group are likely to incur. This risk pooling works better in larger numbers. A statistician would be unsurprised if one group of 250 had four cases of cancer while three others had none. But a single group of 10,000 people is much more likely to remain near the nationwide average, and if each of the 10,000 people pays just a little extra,