Skip to main content

The Problem of Diffuse Costs and Concentrated Benefits

Do you ever find yourself observing a seemingly illogical government program, spending decision, or other strange practice and ask “how is it that no one has fixed that?” If you are like me, you encounter this phenomenon regularly. This often takes the form of a curious headline (Save Federal Funding for the Cowboy Poets!) that most people see and can’t believe is real. I would like to suggest that this phenomenon often results from the problem of diffuse costs and concentrated benefits.

To understand this concept, consider a hypothetical law that assessed a $1 tax on everyone in the United States with the proceeds to be given to one individual for unrestricted use as he sees fit. The people harmed by such a law—the individual taxpayers—will not be very motivated to spend the time and effort to convince Congress to change the law. They might resent the dollar taken from them for a silly cause they don’t support, but the lost dollar isn’t worth the trouble of doing something about it.

On the other hand, it’s hard to imagine something that would motivate the recipient more than the prospect of receiving an easy $350 million. He would fight hard to keep such a law in place, hiring lobbyists, running public information campaigns about all the wonderful things he would do with the money, and donating to the campaigns of elected officials. In fact, he would probably be willing to spend upwards of $349 million on such an effort.

Often, the benefits of a given policy are concentrated in a relatively small number of people or interests (in my hypothetical, an army of one), yet the costs are spread out (diffuse) to a great many. The impetus for individual action to maintain or change the policy is very real for the beneficiaries, and virtually nonexistent for the payers.

While this phenomenon is perhaps most easily identified in our tax policy, it is repeated throughout our public policy debates. Why is it so difficult to close a military base? Why do restrictive occupational licensing regimes persist? Why does overall government spending regularly increase? Why do silly or bloated programs just get more bloated? In each case, the many paying for or harmed by the policy are harmed only a little bit by each program, whereas the few who benefit profit greatly.

Perhaps nowhere is this problem more prevalent than in the practice of levying taxes in order to pay for corporate subsidies. Consider the extraordinary cost of Oklahoma’s wind energy subsidies, and perhaps more revealing, the herculean effort to protect those subsidies. But, as a payor of that program, could you pinpoint exactly how much your contribution to the wind subsidy was and when it started? Did you even notice it? Probably not.

So what is the solution? Frankly, no easy fix exists. By its very nature, this problem is extraordinarily difficult to address. But it would be a good start for our policymakers to at least be aware of the problem. Legislators, when faced with legislation or budgeting decisions, ought to constantly ask themselves, “Who benefits from this?” “Who pays the costs?” Lobbyists often have extensive knowledge of particular policy matters and can marshal persuasive arguments on behalf of their clients' interests. There is nothing wrong with using them as a resource in evaluating legislation. But legislators should keep in mind that lobbyists represent paying clients, not the public at large.

On the benefit side of the equation, we should view any government expenditure that does not confer a near universal benefit on the public with extreme skepticism. As for cost, legislators owe it to taxpayers, who cannot be at every committee hearing, office meeting, or floor debate--much less watch how every tax dime is spent--to view every government expenditure as if it were coming right out of legislators’ own pockets. Such a perspective has a way of concentrating the mind in a manner never achieved when costs are viewed as just a little bit at a time spread out across millions of people. It may be trite to point out that individuals are more judicious with their own money than when spending other people's money, but that makes it no less true.

Benjamin Lepak is Legal Fellow at the 1889 Institute. He can be reached at blepak@1889institute.org.

The opinions expressed in this blog are those of the author, and do not necessarily reflect the official position of 1889 Institute.

Popular posts from this blog

1889 Institute's Statement Regarding School Closures

The 1889 Institute, an Oklahoma think tank, has released the following statement regarding Joy Hofmeister’s proposal to keep schools closed for the remainder of the school year. We at the 1889 Institute consider Joy Hofmeister’s proposal to close Oklahoma’s schools for the rest of the school year a gross overreaction to the coronavirus situation. Even in the best of times and circumstances, suddenly shifting every student in the state from traditional classrooms to online distance learning will have negative educational consequences. This in addition to the economic burden on two-earner families forced to completely reorder their lives with schools closed. We believe many of our leaders have overreacted to worst-case scenarios presented by well-intended health experts with no training or sense of proportion in weighing the collateral damage of shutting down our economy versus targeting resources to protect the truly vulnerable. We say reopen the schools and stop the madness. ...

Can Government Force You to Close Your Business?

1889 Institute takes no position on whether any or all of these measures are warranted or necessary, or whether their economic fallout would inflict more human suffering than they prevent. We are simply evaluating whether they are legal.   With the unprecedented (in the last 100 years at least) reaction surrounding the outbreak of Covid-19, questions that few living legal scholars have considered are suddenly relevant.   Can a quarantine be ordered?   Can a mass quarantine, lockdown, or “cordon sanitaire” be ordered? Can businesses be ordered to change their behavior?   Can businesses be ordered to close? Can state governments order these measures? Can local governments order these measures? My legal brief addresses these issues from a statutory point of view; it is clear that state law gives the governor and mayors broad authority in a state of emergency. They must, of course, do so in a neutral way that they reasonably believe will help preve...

Even If Pandemic Models Were Right, Were Covid Lockdowns Wrong?

1889 has been quite critical of pandemic modeling that government officials have relied on for their Covid-19 response. We have also criticized shutdown orders in light of flaws in the models. But let’s assume for a moment that the worst predictions really would have come true if nothing was done. Even in those worst case scenarios, it’s fair to ask if our governments did the right thing. Were involuntary shutdowns justified, or would people have found a way to both limit the contagion and maintain some level of productivity? Was putting healthy citizens under house arrest acceptable even if they were willing to risk infection?   While large groups of people are often compared to herd animals, we are not sheep. We don’t behave like animals. We can, have, and will step up when our communities are in danger. When government and journalists give incomplete or false information, people will act irrationally. Depending on the situation, some will blindly follow the first aut...

COVID Inspires Tyranny for the "Good" of Its Victims

The Christian philosopher, C.S. Lewis, once said, "Of all tyrannies, a tyranny sincerely exercised for the good of its victims may be the most oppressive. It would be better to live under robber barons than under omnipotent moral busybodies." The moral busybodies C.S Lewis warns of reminds me of those who would have Americans give up their liberty to combat COVID-19.   A recent Oklahoman op-ed compared COVID-19 to World War II, stating that the number of deaths from COVID-19 is approaching the number that died fighting for this country and the freedoms it protects. This comparison is, of course, nonsense. This suggests that a virus with a high survivability rate is an equivalent threat to the Nazi and Japanese regimes that brutally murdered millions. The piece uses wartime rationing of meat and cheese, a sacrifice necessary to ensure men on the front lines had adequate nutrition, to justify Americans accepting counterproductive lockdowns in exchange for additional stimulus c...